← Back to year fins.2023.2 Issue Contents

Should We Assume the Discount Rate to Be One of the Risk Factors

Jan Kaczmarzyk

Abstract: Financial models implemented in corporate finance mostly rely on the discounted cash flow valuation approach. The basic concepts behind various forms of a discounted cash flow valuation are the present value of an asset and the net present value of an asset. Both concepts use a discount rate as a required rate of return for investors or broadly investors and lenders together depending on a particular analytical situation and the type of free cash flow stream. The Monte Carlo simulation is the ultimate solution for considering nearly all possible scenarios in presumably any discounted cash flow valuation. The Author of this paper argues that a discount rate expresses an investor’s cur-rent requirement and should be respectively perceived as a parameter only. The consequences of qualifying a required rate of return (a discount rate) as a risk factor in a dis-counted cash flow valuation are depicted in the paper using a free cash flow financial model of an asset being a hypothetical publicly traded enterprise. The case study is a discounted cash flow valuation using the Monte Carlo simulation for risk analysis. The various sets of assumptions are considered to explain the consequences of qualifying a required rate of return in a discounted cash flow model as a risk factor. As has been in-dicated in the paper, the discount rate as an additional risk factor with an attributed probability distribution increases the volatility of a risk variable. The distribution of a risk variable becomes more flattened then. In previous studies, some Authors indicated that a discount rate could be considered a risk factor in the Monte Carlo simulation (Krysiak 2000, Damodaran 2018).

DOWNLOAD PDF
DOWNLOAD RIS METADATA
<a href="https://dx.doi.org/10.15611/fins.2023.2.01">DOI: 10.15611/fins.2023.2.01</a> <p>JEL Classification: G32</p> <p>Keywords: corporate finance, valuation, DCF, riskanalysis, Monte Carlo simulation</p> <h2>1. Introduction </h2> <p>Financial models implemented in corporate finance mostly rely on the discounted cash flow valuation approach. The basic concepts behind various forms of a discounted cash flow valuation are the present value of an asset and the net present value of an asset. The author used the present value concept to estimate the value of an asset (e.g. in an enterprise valuation, a bond or a credit valuation, a derivative valuation, etc.) whereas we specifically focus on a net present value to assess the profitability of an asset (e.g. in an investment project profitability appraisal). Both concepts use a discount rate as a required rate of return for investors or broadly investors and lenders together depending on a particular analytical situation and the type of free cash flow stream.</p> <p>The traditional approach to discounted cash flow valuation results in a single scenario built on the analyst’s specific assumptions. However, a volatile economic environment suggests intuitively an infinite number of scenarios that might happen in the real world. The ultimate solution for considering nearly all possible scenarios in presumably any discounted cash flow valuation is the Monte Carlo simulation (Brealey et al., 2014; Golden and Golden, 1987; Hertz, 1964; Kroese et al., 2014). In terms of risk analysis, risk factors are those financial model inputs that are subject to the economic environment and its volatility. The others are only parameters. Nonetheless, there is an infinite number of risk factor scenarios, while there is no more than one scenario of an input being a parameter.</p> <p>Some studies indicated that a discount rate could be considered a risk factor (Damodaran, 2018; Krysiak, 2000), whereas this author argues that a discount rate expresses an investor’s current requirement and should be respectively perceived as a parameter. The paper shows the consequences of taking up an assumption in the Monte Carlo simulation which would qualify a discount rate as a risk factor.</p> <h2>2. Theoretical Background </h2> <p>Although the difference between present value and net present value is technically very simple, it is conceptually truly significant. The present value concept is based on a cash flow stream that excludes a possible payment or a series of possible payments for an asset. Estimating the present value of an asset gives an analyst a possible value of an asset – a hypothetical payment. If an investor paid the present value for an asset and received the exact estimated cash flow stream in the considered time horizon, they would certainly achieve their required rate of return being here the internal rate of return of the transaction. One can conclude that the present value is a value of an asset that resembles both its ability to generate a certain cash flow stream and the investor’s profitability requirement. Net present value additionally considers a payment or a series of payments for an asset (e.g. a market price of a stock or a bond, a capital expenditure or expenditures related to an investment project, etc.) and depicts the profitability of a transaction. The basic rule here is widely known and accepted – if a payment for an asset was lower (higher) than its present value, the net present value would be positive (negative) and the investor would realize an internal rate of return higher (lower) than their required rate of return. The concepts of present value, net present value, and internal rate of return are quite dated (e.g. Fischer, 1930; Gordon, 1955; Lorie and Savage, 1955; Williams, 1938) but they remain truly relevant for modern finance. The present value concept has successfully been the core of the value-based management idea so far (Rappaport, 1999; Rappaport, 2006), whereas the net present value concept is deservedly classified as one of the most important concepts in modern finance (Brealey et al., 2014).</p> <p>An analyst who decides to perform a discounted cash flow valuation must estimate 1) a cash flow stream and 2) a required rate of return. The question is whether cash flow stream components and a required rate of return are all risk factors. Beginning with the definition of a risk factor, a risk factor is technically a financial model input variable that may vary from its forecast value due to the economic environment and its volatility. Assuming that a required rate of return was a risk factor would mean that an investor would be uncertain about the level of the satisfying required rate of return. An investor is actually always uncertain about the final payment or the series of payments – not uncertain about their own required rate of return at the moment of valuation. Therefore, a discounted cash flow valuation is performed to find the present value which could assure the investor’s required rate of return; thus the investor may decide whether the offered payment is acceptable.</p> <p>In terms of own equity, one thinks about shareholders’ required rates of return. These rates were successfully estimated using the dividend model (Gordon and Shapiro, 1956) or the CAPM (Lintner, 1965; Mossin, 1966; Sharpe, 1964; Treynor 1962) for assets being stocks of publicly traded enterprises so far. For non-publicly traded companies, usually the CAPM with Hamada’s correction was involved (Damodaran, 2012; Hamada, 1972). The dividend model derives a required rate of return as the internal rate of return of a cash flow stream including the current price of a stock and an infinite series of dividends. Through the CAPM a required rate of return is the sum of a risk-free rate and the difference between a market risk rate and the risk-free rate adjusted by systemic risk. Hamada’s equation changes the required rate of return to reflect the financial leverage of a particular enterprise. A required rate of return derived this way is mostly affected by the historical period considered or the interval chosen. Therefore, it may differ depending on subjective assumptions of a particular financial analyst and may be even, easily manipulated – but it still helps to find a reasonable and widely accepted level of a required rate of return in a particular analytical situation. The fact that a required rate of return derived through the mentioned or similar models may differ due to the period and/or the interval of the historical data taken into account, does not mean that a required rate of return of an investor is somehow volatile at the moment of valuation. It is just an estimated investor’s requirement, broadly – a minimum value of a required rate of return they could have accepted.</p> <p>A cash flow stream is simultaneously affected by numerous risk factors and parameters. Therefore, as there is no single scenario of a cash flow stream that may happen in the future – there is logically an infinite number of possibilities due to infinite combinations of possible values of risk factors – due to infinite future states, the economic environment may fall into. The solution for considering nearly all possible scenarios of cash flows in a discounted cash flow valuation is the Monte Carlo simulation (Hertz, 1964; Kroese et al., 2014). In fact, this simulation is not quite new and was not even designed specifically for finance (Ulam et al., 1947) but is very relevant and useful. The scenarios of cash flows are the direct source of the present value and net present value scenarios respectively. As a consequence, the outcome of the Monte Carlo simulation is then the probability distribution of possible present values or net present values (or the other cash flow-based profitability measures).</p> <p>The Monte Carlo simulation results in a probability distribution of a risk variable. Typically, risk factors are financial or non-financial figures like unit prices, unit costs, exchange rates, interest rates, fixed costs, unit demands, etc. Whenever the Monte Carlo simulation is involved, every input variable being a risk factor must be depicted with a probability distribution chosen objectively, quasi-objectively, or subjectively. Due to interdependencies between them, a correlation matrix must be specified too (Kaczmarzyk, 2016; compare Hull, 2018; Vose, 2008). The result of the Monte Carlo simulation is the probability distribution of a risk variable which reflects simultaneous, interdependent, and non-linear changes in risk factors. The concept of qualifying the discount rate as an additional risk factor (Damodaran, 2018; Krysiak, 2000,) results in attributing an additional probability distribution. This could be a uniform probability distribution (e.g. Damodaran, 2018, p. 35) or a triangle probability distribution (e.g. Krysiak, 2000, p. 68). The variability of a discount rate will affect the volatility of a risk variable and blur the influence of the other risk factors. The aim of the paper was to show how a required rate of return qualified as a risk factor affects the result of a DCF analysis.</p> <h2>3. Methodology</h2> <p>The consequences of qualifying a required rate of return (a discount rate) as a risk factor in a discounted cash flow valuation are shown in the paper using a free-cash-flow-to-firm financial model of an asset being a hypothetical publicly traded enterprise. The model estimates the intrinsic value per share and is based directly on the present value concept (Figure 1).</p> <p> <img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image1.png" /> </p> <p><strong>Fig. 1.</strong> The financial model Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>The model starts with the revenue forecast (Row 4) with a certain level of revenue growth rate (Row 3). The operational costs less depreciation (Row 5), fixed assets (Row 10), and net working capital (Row 13) are derived from the respective ratios indicating their relation to the revenues (Rows 5, 7, and 12). Then, the cash flow stream (Row 23) is calculated. The required rate of return in the model is the weighted average cost of capital (Row 28). The cash flow stream is affected by two undisputable risk factors: the revenue growth rate and the ratio of operational costs less depreciation as well as by the questionable risk factor – the required rate of return. The revenue growth rate and the ratio of operational costs less depreciation are assumed to be the same in every single period of the detailed projection. The model output is the intrinsic value of a single stock.</p> <p><strong>Table 1.</strong> Sets of assumptions</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th>Set 1</th> <th>Fixed required rate</th> <th>Fixed revenue growth rate</th> <th>Fixed operational cost ratio</th> </tr> </thead> <tr><td>Set 2</td> <td>Uniform required rate</td> <td>Fixed revenue growth rate</td> <td>Fixed operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 3</td> <td>Triangular required rate</td> <td>Fixed revenue growth rate</td> <td>Fixed operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 4</td> <td>Normal required rate</td> <td>Fixed revenue growth rate</td> <td>Fixed operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 5</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Uniform revenue growth rate</td> <td>Fixed operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 6</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Triangular revenue growth rate</td> <td>Fixed operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 7</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Normal revenue growth rate</td> <td>Fixed operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 8</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Fixed revenue growth rate</td> <td>Uniform operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 9</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Fixed revenue growth rate</td> <td>Triangular operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 10</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Fixed revenue growth rate</td> <td>Normal operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 11</td> <td>Fixed required rate</td> <td>Normal revenue growth rate</td> <td>Normal operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 12</td> <td>Uniform required rate</td> <td>Normal revenue growth rate</td> <td>Normal operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 13</td> <td>Fixed required rate (lower)</td> <td>Normal revenue growth rate</td> <td>Normal operational cost ratio</td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 14</td> <td>Fixed required rate (higher)</td> <td>Normal revenue growth rate</td> <td>Normal operational cost ratio</td> </tr> </table> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>The case study is a discounted cash flow valuation using the Monte Carlo simulation for risk analysis. The various sets of assumptions (Table 1) are considered to explain the consequences of qualifying a required rate of return in a discounted cash flow model as a risk factor. The model was developed using Microsoft Excel 365 and the simulations performed using Palisade @RISK 8.2.1.</p> <h2>4. Case study</h2> <p>The first set of assumptions (Figure 2) qualifies only the required rate of return as a risk factor to depict how a fixed required rate of return may affect the valuation. Obviously, the fixed required rate of return level results in the fixed intrinsic value level (Set 1). The higher (lower) the required rate of return level, the lower (higher) the intrinsic value of an enterprise would occur.</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th>Set 1</th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image2.png" /></th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image3.png" /></th> </tr> </thead> </table> <p><strong>Fig. 2.</strong> Fixed required rate of return, fixed revenue growth rate, and fixed operational cost ratio</p> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>If the required rate of return of the investor was assumed to be a risk factor, it would reflect a very hypothetical situation in which the investor would be uncertain about an adequate required rate of return level (Figure 3). The investor could assume then, e.g. that their required rate of return belonged to a certain range but every level within this range had the same probability. To reflect such a phenomenon, a uniform probability for the required rate of return should have been chosen (Set 2). The probability distribution of the intrinsic value precisely reflects the way how a certain level of the required rate of return affects the intrinsic value. Namely, the required rate of return affects the intrinsic value in a nonlinear way. For the same relative increase or decrease of the initial required rate of return level there occurs an incommensurate change in the intrinsic value. Moreover, the probability of the intrinsic value shows precisely that the lowest intrinsic value has the highest probability of occurrence, whereas the highest intrinsic value has the lowest probability. The phenomenon of the nonlinear type of interdependency between the required rate of the return level and the respective intrinsic value would also be clearly visible if the investor applied another type of theoretical probability distribution to reflect their beliefs. For example, they could use a simple triangular probability distribution to reflect their belief that an adequate required rate of return belonged to a certain range in which extreme values had the lowest probability and there was a certain level of the required rate of return between them with the highest chance of occurrence from the investor’s point of view (Set 3).</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th>Set 2</th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image4.png" /></th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image5.png" /></th> </tr> </thead> <tr><td>Set 3</td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image6.png" /></td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image7.png" /></td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 4</td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image8.png" /></td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image9.png" /></td> </tr> </table> <p><strong>Fig. 3.</strong> Variable required rate of return, fixed revenue growth rate, and fixed operational cost ratio</p> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>The way in which a required rate of return affects an intrinsic value would be a little bit less visible but still relevant if a normal probability distribution was chosen (Set 4) to reflect investor’s requirements. It should be emphasised that a symmetrical required rate of return probability distribution generally results in an asymmetrical probability distribution of the intrinsic value.</p> <p>The interpretation of the intrinsic value probability distribution would change significantly when the investor had a fixed required rate of return but assumed that the growth of revenues could be the only risk factor (Figure 4). This would be a reasonable assumption because, at the moment of valuation, the investor would not know how the economic environment could develop and how this all might affect the entrepreneurial activity of their enterprise. An infinite number of possible revenue growth paths results in the respective infinite number of intrinsic value scenarios. Different probability distributions represent different types of possible investor’s assumptions (Sets 5, 6 and 7). The impact of the growth rate level on the intrinsic value is also nonlinear which is worth emphasising here.</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th>Set 5</th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image10.png" /></th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image11.png" /></th> </tr> </thead> <tr><td>Set 6</td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image12.png" /></td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image13.png" /></td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 7</td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image14.png" /></td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image15.png" /></td> </tr> </table> <p><strong>Fig. 4</strong>. Fixed required rate of return, variable revenue growth rate, and fixed operational costs ratio</p> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>Assuming that the ratio of the operational costs was a risk factor would also be reasonable. The probability distribution of the intrinsic value is symmetrical due to possible changes in the ratio of the operational costs (Figure 5).</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th>Set 8</th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image16.png" /></th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image17.png" /></th> </tr> </thead> <tr><td>Set 9</td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image18.png" /></td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image19.png" /></td> </tr> <tr><td>Set 10</td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image20.png" /></td> <td><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image21.png" /></td> </tr> </table> <p><strong>Fig. 5</strong>. Fixed required rate of return, fixed revenue growth rate, and variable operational cost ratio</p> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>The Monte Carlo simulation is used in finance especially to examine the influence of the simultaneous impact of risk factors. The volatility of the intrinsic value would rise if both risk factors were taken into account at the same time (Figure 6, Set 11). If the required rate of return was added as a third risk factor (e.g. uniformly distributed), the volatility of the intrinsic value would grow again (Figure 6, Set 12). Although technically possible, such an approach leads to a blurred picture of risk. The volatility of the economic environment is raised by uncertain expectations of an investor.</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th><p>Set 11</p> <p>Set 12</p></th> <th><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image22.png" /></th> </tr> </thead> </table> <p><strong>Fig. 6</strong>. Fixed and variable required rate of return, variable revenue growth rate, and variable operational cost ratio</p> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <table class="table table-bordered"> <colgroup> <col></col> <col></col> </colgroup> <thead> <tr><th>Set 11 Set 13 Set 14</th> <th><p><img src="/articles/2023/Kaczmarzyk_sklad/media/image23.png" /></p> <table class="table table-bordered"><colgroup><col></col><col></col><col></col><col></col></colgroup><thead><tr><th> </th><th>Set 11, Fixed required rate, Normal revenue growth rate, Normal operational cost ratio</th> <th>Set 13, Fixed required rate (lower), Normal revenue growth rate, Normal operational cost ratio</th> <th>Set 14, Fixed required rate (higher), Normal revenue growth rate, Normal operational cost ratio</th> </tr></thead><tr><td>Expected Value</td> <td>104.16</td> <td>202.29</td> <td>39.01</td> </tr><tr><td>Standard deviation</td> <td>41.10</td> <td>53.05</td> <td>33.60</td> </tr><tr><td>Coefficient of variation</td> <td>0.39</td> <td>0.26</td> <td>0.86</td> </tr></table></th> </tr> </thead> </table> <p><strong>Fig. 7</strong>. Different fixed required rates of return, variable revenue growth rate and variable operational cost ratio</p> <p>Source: own elaboration.</p> <p>Even though a volatile required rate of return blurs the risk associated with an asset, it somehow is a volatile input because it may differ among different investors valuing an asset with different required rates of return. Having set the same assumptions for all risk factors besides the required rate of return (Figure 7), the investor with the lowest required rate of return will face the highest absolute (lowest relative) volatility of the intrinsic value (Set 13), whereas the investor with the highest – will face the lowest (highest) volatility (Set 14).</p> <h2>5. Conclusion</h2> <p>The discount rate as a risk factor with an attributed probability distribution affects a risk variable in a nonlinear way. This can be easily confirmed by qualifying the discount rate as the only risk factor during simulation. Regarding a uniformly distributed discount rate, namely a discount rate with a certain range of possible values with the same probability of occurrence, one can expect different probabilities of a risk variable, such as an intrinsic value. Depending on a risk factor, influence can be nonlinear (e.g. the growth rate of revenues) or linear (e.g. the share of variable costs). The discount rate as an additional risk factor with an attributed probability distribution increases the volatility of a risk variable. Then, the distribution of a risk variable becomes more flattened.</p> <p>In the case of different discount rate levels representing different investors with different expectations, one must emphasise that the higher the discount rate, the lower the present value, and consequently, the lower the intrinsic value. At the same time, the lower the absolute volatility, the higher the relative volatility of the present value, and consequently, the intrinsic value.</p> <p>References</p> <p>Brealey, R., Myers, S., and Allen, F. (2014). <em>Principles of Corporate Finance</em>. McGraw-Hill.</p> <p>Damodaran, A. (2012). <em>Investment Valuation. Tools and Techniques for Determining the Value of Any Asset</em>. 3rd Edition. John Wiley &amp; Sons.</p> <p>Damodaran A. (2018). <em>Facing Up To Uncertainty: Using Probabilistic Approaches in Valuation</em>. SRRN: 1-65. Retrieved September 4, 2019 from <a href="https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3237778">https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3237778</a></p> <p>Fischer, I. (1930), The Theory of Interest. The Macmillan Company.</p> <p>Golden, C., and Golden, M. (1987). Beyond “What If”: A Risk-Oriented Capital Budgeting Model. <em>Journal of Information Systems</em>, <em>1</em>(2), 53-64.</p> <p>Gordon M. (1955). The Payoff Period and the Rate of Profit. <em>The Journal of Business</em>, <em>4</em>(28), 253-260.</p> <p>Gordon, M., and Shapiro, E. (1956). Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit. <em>Management Science</em>, <em>1</em>(3), 102-110.</p> <p>Hamada, R. (1972). The Effect of The Firm's Capital Structure on The Systematic Risk of Common Stocks. <em>Journal of Finance</em>, <em>2</em>(27), 435-452.</p> <p>Hertz, D. (1964). Risk Analysis in Capital Investment. <em>Harvard Business Review</em>, <em>42</em>(1), 95-106.</p> <p>Hull, J. (2018). <em>Risk Management and Financial Institutions</em> (5th edition). John Wiley &amp; Sons.</p> <p>Kaczmarzyk, J. (2016). Reflecting Interdependencies between Risk Factors in Corporate risk Modeling using Monte Carlo Simulation. <em>Econometrics. Ekonometria. Advances in Applied Data Analytics</em>, <em>2</em>(52), 98-107.</p> <p>Kroese, D., Brereton, T., Taimre, T., and Botev, Z. (2014). Why the Monte Carlo method is so important today. WIREs Comput Stat, <em>6</em>(6), 386-392.</p> <p>Krysiak, Z. (2000). Analiza symulacyjna – narzędzie do poprawnego wyznaczania wartości firmy. <em>Nasz Rynek Kapitałowy</em>, 11(119), 68-71.</p> <p>Lintner, J. (1965). The Valuation of Risk Assets and The Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets. <em>The Review of Economics and Statistics</em>, <em>1</em>(47), 13-37.</p> <p>Lorie, J. and Savage, L. (1955). Three Problems in Rationing Capital. <em>The Journal of Business</em>, <em>4</em>(28), 229-239.</p> <p>Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market. <em>Econometrica</em>, <em>4</em>(34), 768-783.</p> <p>Rappaport, A. (1999). <em>Wartość dla akcjonariuszy. Poradnik menedżera i inwestora</em>. WIG-Press.</p> <p>Rappaport, A. (2006). Ten Ways to Create Shareholder Value. <em>Harvard Business Review</em>, <em>9</em>(84), 66-77.</p> <p>Sharpe, W. (1964). Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk. <em>Journal of Finance</em>, <em>3</em>(19), 425-442.</p> <p>Treynor, J. (1999). Toward a Theory of Market Value of Risky Assets. In R. Korajczyk (Ed.), <em>Asset Pricing and Portfolio Performance</em>. Risk Books.</p> <p>Ulam, S., Richtmyer, R., and Neumann, J. (1947). <em>Statistical Methods in Neutron Diffusion: Los Alamos Scientific Laboratory report LAMS-551</em>. Retrieved December, 12, 2019 from <a href="https://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft9g50091s;chunk.id=d0e2404;doc.view=print">https://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft9g50091s;chunk.id=d0e2404;doc.view=print</a></p> <p>Vose, D. (2008). <em>Risk Analysis</em> (3rd Edition). John Wiley &amp; Sons.</p> <p>Williams, J. (1938). <em>The Theory of Investment Value</em>. North-Holland Publishing Company.</p>

Table of contents

Indexing Services
& Digital Libraries

  • cejsh logo
  • ceeol logo
  • Biblioteka Nauki logo
  • bazekon logo
  • ebsco logo
  • erih plus logo
  • dbc logo

Newsletter